Intelligence and the Wealth and Poverty of Nations


Intelligence and the Wealth and Poverty of Nations
RICHARD LYNN
University of Ulster, Coleraine, Northern Ireland
TATU VANHANEN
University of Helsinki, Finland
SUMMARY.
National IQs assessed by the Progressive Matrices were calculated for 60 nations and
examined in relation to per capita incomes in the late 1990s and to post World War Two rates of
economic growth. It was found that national IQs are correlated at 0.757 with real GDP (Gross
Domestic Product) per capita 1998 and 0.706 with per capita GNP (Gross National Product)
1998; and at 0.605 with the growth of per capita GDP 1950-90 and 0.643 with growth of per
capita GNP 1976-98. The results are interpreted in terms of a causal model in which population
IQs are the major determinant of the wealth and poverty of nations in the contemporary world.
INTRODUCTION
The causes of the inequalities in income and wealth between nations have been discussed for
some two and a half centuries. In 1748 Montesquieu published De l'Esprit des Lois in which he
proposed that temperate climates were more favorable to economic development than tropical
climates. In 1776 this problem was discussed by Adam Smith in his Wealth of Nations, in which
he proposed that the skills of the population are the principal factor responsible for national
differences in incomes and wealth.
Since these early attempts to analyse this problem, numerous other theories have been
advanced. These theories fall into four principal categories. First, climatic theories are still
proposed. Their leading exponent in recent times is Kamarck (1976) who argues that tropical
climates are unfavorable for economic development because the heat and humidity reduce the
efficiency of working capacities, impair the productivity of the land and provide a favorable
environment for debilitating diseases. This explains the difference between what is sometimes
called "the rich north" with its temperate climate and "the poor south" with its predominantly
tropical climate.
Diamond (1998) presents similar arguments on the crucial significance of climatic and
geographical factors.
The second major contemporary explanation is "dependency theory". This proposes that the
economically developed capitalist nations are responsible for the poverty of the underdeveloped
nations because they dominate the world economy, force the rest of the world into economic
dependency, and pay low prices for Third World agricultural products and natural resources.
Some of the leading exponents of this theory are Frank (1969, 1996), dos Santos (1993, 1996),
Wallerstein (1998) and Valenzuela and Valenzuela (1998); see also Seligson and Pass%7Å„-Smith
(1998).
Third, there is the neoliberal theory. This proposes that the major factor responsible for national
differences in economic development consists of the presence of free markets as opposed to
command, socialist and communist economies. Bates (1993) and Weede (1993) are leading
recent exponents of this theory.
Fourth, there are a variety of psychological theories which argue for the importance of
differences in attitudes, values and motivations. The first major theory of this kind was Weber's
(1904) theory that the Protestant work ethic explained the more rapid economic development of
northern Europe as compared with the Catholic south from the sixteenth century onwards. Later
theorists in this tradition include McClelland (1976) who advanced the similar concept of
achievement motivation. Several economists, while not endorsing the theories of Weber or
McClelland, are sympathetic to this kind of explanation and propose what are generally termed
"cultural" factors as major contributors to national differences in economic development. Landes
writes of the importance of culture "in the sense of inner values and attitudes that guide a
population" (1998, p. 516). Many economists have taken eclectic positions in which they argue
that several of these factors contribute to national differences in incomes and wealth.
We believe it has never been suggested that national differences in intelligence might play
some role in national differences in economic development. It is widely assumed that the
peoples of all nations have the same average level of intelligence. For instance, Kofi Annan, the
United Nations Secretary General, asserted in April 2000 that intelligence "is one commodity
equally distributed among the world's people" (Hoyos and Littlejohns, 2000). It is known in
psychology that this is incorrect and that there are large differences in average levels of
intelligence between different nations. Reviews of the literature have shown that in relation to
average IQs of 100 in Britain and the United States, the peoples of north east Asia have
average IQs of around 105 and the peoples of sub-Saharan Africa have average IQs of around
70 (Lynn, 1991).
In view of these differences, it seems a reasonable hypothesis that national differences in
intelligence may be a factor contributing to national differences in wealth. This is a promising
hypothesis for two reasons. First, it is well established that intelligence is a determinant of
earnings among individuals; and second, several studies have shown that the intelligence of
groups is related to their average earnings. The earlier American research literature, up to 1970,
on the relationship of intelligence to earnings among individuals was summarized by Jencks
(1972) who concluded that the best estimate was expressed by a correlation of .35. Later
studies have confirmed this conclusion. Brown and Reynolds (1995) examined the relation
between IQ measured in early adulthood and earnings approximately 12 years later for samples
of 24,819 whites and 4,008 blacks and reported correlations of .327 and .126, respectively.
Hunter and Hunter (1984) report correlations between .25 and .60 for different types of
occupations. Murray (1998) has examined the National Longitudinal Study of Youth sample for
the relation between IQ measured in adolescence and income in the late twenties to mid-thirties
and found a correlation of .37. Most students of this question have concluded that IQ is a cause
of income because IQs are established quite early in childhood and predict incomes achieved in
adulthood (Duncan, Featherman and Duncan, 1972; Jensen, 1998). It is estimated by Li (1975)
that childhood IQ is correlated .83 with adult IQ. The relation between childhood IQ and adult
income is present when parental socio-economic status is controlled (Duncan, Featherman and
Duncan, 1972; Jencks, 1979).
The positive association between IQ and income among individuals led to the expectation that
there would be positive associations between the average IQs of groups and their average
earnings. We believe that the existence of such an association was first reported by Davenport
and Remmers (1950) in a study in which the population units were the states of the United
States. They obtained IQ scores from tests administered in 1943 to more than 300,000 young
men in high schools and colleges as part of selection for placement in training programs for the
armed services. The test was composed of verbal, mathematical and scientific items and was
described as "a combination of a group intelligence test and a general educational achievement
test" (p. 110). They calculated the average score for each state, examined this in relation to the
state's per capita income and found a correlation of .81.
The positive relationship between the average IQs of groups and their average incomes has
also been found in studies carried out in Europe. A study of the British Isles examined the
relation between average IQs in thirteen regions obtained in the 1940s and 1950s and per
capita incomes in 1965. The average IQs fell within the relatively narrow range between 102.1
in London and 96.0 in Ireland. The correlation between average IQs and incomes was .73
(Lynn, 1979). A similar study for France examined the relation between average IQs in 90
"departments" (regions) obtained from testing approximately 257,000 young men conscripted
into the armed services in the mid-1950s and per capita incomes in 1974. The correlation
between IQs and earnings was .61 (Lynn, 1980). The same relationship has been found in
Spain in a study in which average IQs for 48 regions were calculated from approximately
130,000 military conscripts for the mid-1960s. The correlation between these and average
regional incomes was .65 (Lynn, 1981). In view of these relationships it seems a promising
hypothesis that a positive relationship would be present between the average IQs of the
populations of nations and their average earnings. It is this hypothesis that we are now about to
investigate.
METHOD
This study presents data for 60 countries for national IQs, per capita incomes in 1998, and
economic growth 1950-1998 and examines their relationships by the statistical techniques of
correlation and regression analyses.
National IQs
National IQs have been calculated from normative data obtained in 60 countries for the Colored
and Standard Progressive Matrices. The reasons for using these data are that the Progressive
Matrices is the most widely used test in cross-cultural research, is non-verbal and hence is likely
to yield more valid cross cultural data than verbal tests which require translation, is among the
best measures of g, and the rate of secular increase is well established. The data have been
obtained from the bibliographies of Progressive Matrices studies compiled by Court (1980) and
Court and Raven (1995), from the data given by Raven in a series of manuals and research
supplements for the Progressive Matrices, and from the Raven archive.
The Standard Progressive Matrices was constructed in Britain in the 1930s and was first
published in 1938 with norms for 6-15 year olds and adults. This was followed by the publication
in 1947 of the Colored Progressive Matrices, a simpler test suitable for 5-11 year olds. The
Standard Progressive Matrices was renormed for 6 to 15 year olds in Britain 1979. A norm table
is provided by Raven (1981) giving percentile equivalents of raw scores for half year age
groups. The procedure for calculating the IQ of a country in which norms have been obtained
for the Standard Progressive Matrices is to read off the raw scores of the 50th percentile from
the norm table and obtain the British 1979 percentile. This is then converted to the British IQ
equivalent using a conversion table. The raw score of the 50th percentile is the median IQ
rather than the mean. Several studies have provided mean raw scores in addition to the
medians and these show that means and medians are virtually identical. In most countries in
which Progressive Matrices data have been collected norms have been given for a number of
age groups. IQs are calculated for each of these and averaged to give a single national IQ. This
IQ is then adjusted for the secular rise of the IQ which has been 2 IQ points per decade for the
Standard Progressive Matrices in Britain over the period 1938-1979 (Lynn and Hampson,
1986). All national IQs are therefore expressed in relation to a British IQ of 100.
Norms for the Standard Progressive were collected for adults for Britain in 1992 and for the
United States for 1993. The norm table for the United States provided by Raven, Court and
Raven (1996) gives the most detailed information consisting of the percentile equivalents of raw
scores. Less information is provided for the British standardization which gives only the raw
score equivalents of the 5th, 10th, 25th, 50th, 75th, 90th and 95th percentiles. The British
medians have been converted to American IQs by the use of the American norm table. The
result of this calculation is that the British IQ is 102 on the American norms. Data for adults from
other countries are converted to American IQs and then adjusted to British IQs by the
subtraction of 2 IQ points.
There are no norms giving detailed percentiles for the Colored Progressive Matrices for Britain,
the United States or elsewhere. To deal with data for the Colored Progressive Matrices, raw
scores are converted to those of the Standard Progressive Matrices using the conversion table
provided by Raven, Court and Raven (1995) and the IQs calculated in the way set out above.
In a few instances median raw scores fall below the 1st percentile of the British and American
norm tables. The 1st percentile is equivalent to an IQ of 65. In these cases the countries are
assigned an IQ of 64. For a number of countries Progressive Matrices data have been collected
for two or more samples. These have been averaged to provide a single mean given to the
nearest whole number.
The IQ for South Africa has been calculated as follows. The study by Owen (1992) gives the
following IQs for the four racial groups. Whites: 94; blacks: 66; coloureds: 82; Indians: 83. The
percentages of the four groups in the population are whites: 14%; blacks: 75%; coloreds: 9%;
Indians: 2% (Ramsay, 1999, p. 158). Weighting the IQs of the four groups by their percentages
in the population gives an IQ for South Africa of 72. The IQ of Singapore has been calculated in
the same way by weighting the IQs of the ethnic groups (Malays, Chinese and Indians in
Singapore) by their numbers in the population. The data on national IQs are shown in Appendix
1 which gives the IQ, the sample size, the test used (Colored or Standard Progressive Matrices)
and the reference. For some countries there are two or more studies of the national IQ. These
have been averaged to give mean IQs for these countries.
Because the concept of national IQ is new, it will be useful to examine its reliability and validity.
To examine its reliability we have taken the sixteen countries for which there are two or more
measures of IQ and calculated the correlation between the two measures. For the countries for
which there are more than two measures (Brazil, Hong Kong, India and Mexico) we have used
the two extreme values. The correlation between the two measures of national IQ is 0.937. This
establishes that the measure of national IQ has high reliability.
To examine the validity of the national IQs we have examined their relation with national
measures of educational attainment. This follows the long established methodology of the
validation of intelligence tests among individuals by showing that they are positively correlated
with test of educational attainment. The measures of education attainment are taken from the
second and third international studies of educational achievement in mathematics and science.
These data are shown in Table 1 for the countries for which we have IQ measures. The
correlations between educational attainment and IQ are shown in the bottom two rows of the
table. Five of the six correlations are statistically significant and establish the validity of the
measures of national IQ.
Table 1.
National Attainments in Math and Science
Country Math Math Math Science Science Science
Australia - 546 530 12.9 562 545
Belgium 20.0 - 546 - - 511
Britain 15.2 513 506 11.7 551 552
Canada 18.4 532 527 13.7 549 531
Czech Rep - 567 564 - 557 574
Denmark - - 502 - - 478
Finland 14.1 - - 15.3 - -
France 15.2 - 538 - - 498
Germany - - 509 - - 531
Hong Kong 16.3 587 588 11.2 533 522
Iran - 429 428 - 415 470
Ireland - 550 527 - 539 538
Israel 18.3 531 522 - 505 524
Italy - - - 13.4 - -
Japan 23.8 597 605 15.4 574 571
Korea - 611 607 15.4 597 565
Netherlands 21.1 577 541 - 557 560
New Zealand 14.1 499 508 - 531 525
Nigeria 9.3 - - - - -
Philippines - - - 9.5 - -
Poland - - - 11.9 - -
Portugal - 475 454 - 480 480
Romania - - 482 - - 486
Russia - - 535 - - 538
Singapore - 625 643 11.2 547 607
Slovak Rep - - 547 - - 544
Slovenia - 552 541 - 546 560
S. Africa - - 354 - - 326
Spain - - 487 - - 517
Switzerland - - 545 - - 522
Thailand 13.1 490 522 - 473 525
U.S.A. 15.1 545 500 13.2 565 534
Correlation with IQ .676 .768 .766 .477 .839 .698
Significance .01 .001 .001 .1 .001 .001
Notes:
Column 1.
13 year olds, Second International Study of Mathematical Achievement, 1982 (Baker and Jones, 1993).
Column 2.
10 year olds, Third International Mathematics and Science Study, 1994-5 (Mullis, 1997).
Column 3.
14 year olds, Third International Mathematics and Science Study, 1994-5, (Benton et al., 1996a).
Column 4.
10 year olds, Second International Study of Science Achievement, 1985 (IEA, 1988).
Column 5.
10 year olds. Third International Mathematics and Science Study, 1994-5 (Martin et al., 1997).
Column 6.
14 year olds, Third International Mathematics and Science Study, 1994-5 (Benton et al., 1996b).
National Wealth and Rates of Economic Growth
National wealth is measured by per capita national income. Strictly speaking, national wealth
and national per capita income are different concepts because national wealth consists of the
value of capital stock, whereas income is income, so we use the term national wealth in the
general sense in which people speak of rich countries and poor countries. We use two
alternative measures of national income: per capita GNP in US dollars and real GDP per capita
in US dollars. The second measure is calculated on the basis of the purchasing power parity of
the country's currency. It is intended "to make more accurate international comparisons of GDP
and its components than those based on official exchange rates, which can be subject to
considerable fluctuation" (Human Development Report, 1997, p. 239). For some countries data
on per capita GNP and real GDP per capita can differ considerably from each other. The basic
difference between GNP and GDP is that GDP comprises the total output of goods and services
for final use produced by an economy by both residents and non-residents within the
geographical boundaries of a nation, whereas GNP comprises GDP plus income from abroad,
which is the income residents receive from abroad, less similar payments made to non-
residents who contribute to the domestic economy. The difference between GNP and GDP is
relatively small for most countries - much smaller than difference between GNP and real GDP -
but in some cases it can be quite substantial (see Gardner, 1998, pp. 22-23; Human
Development Report 1999, p. 254; World Development Report 1999/2000, p. 274).
Most data on per capita GNP are taken from the World Bank's World Development Report
1999/2000 and all data on real GDP per capita from the United Nations Development Program's
(UNDP) Human Development Report 2000. Sources of supplementary data are given at the foot
of Appendix 2. Data for per capita GNP and real GDP per capita used in this paper are for the
year 1998. These are the latest data available to us at the time of writing. These data for per
capita incomes are shown in Appendix 2 for the same countries as in Appendix 1. However, in
Appendix 2 the United Kingdom replaces Britain in Appendix 1.
Economic growth rates are measured as percentage increases in per capita GNP and per
capita GDP. Consistent national differences in economic growth rates over many decades are
responsible for contemporary national differences in GNP and GDP. Our hypothesis that
national differences in IQ are a cause of contemporary national differences in GNP and GDP
entails the prediction that national IQs should be positively correlated with long term rates of
economic growth. We present two tests of this prediction. First, we examine the correlation
between national IQs and economic growth rates of per capita GDP over the period 1950-1990
using the per capita GDP data given by Maddison (1995) for 54 of the countries in our sample.
Second, we examine the correlation between national IQs and economic growth rates of per
capita GNP over the period 1976-1998 using per capita GNP data given in the World Bank's
World Development Reports. From these data we have calculated the percentage changes of
per capita GDP over the period 1950-90 and per capita GNP over the period 1976-98.
These figures are given in Appendix 2.
RESULTS
We examine first the correlations between national IQs and the two measures of national per
capita income. These are presented in Table 2. It shows that the two measures of per capita
national income are highly intercorrelated (.945). It also shows that the correlations between
national IQs and the two measures of per capita national income are strongly positive as
hypothesized. The national IQs are correlated .706 with per capita GNP and .757 with per
capita real GDP. Both correlations are statistically significant at p<.001. We examine next the
relation between national IQs and rates of economic growth. The correlation between national
IQs and economic growth rates of GDP per capita over the period 1950-1990 is .605 (N=54,
p<.001). The correlation between national IQs and economic growth rates of per capita GNP
over the period 1976-1998 is .643 (N=56, p<.001).
It has been suggested by a referee that the mean IQs of sub-Saharan African countries are so
low that they cannot be valid and that they spuriously inflate the correlations between the
national IQs and the measures of per capita income and economic growth. We believe that we
have to some degree met this point by showing in Table 1 that attainment in mathematics in
Nigeria and South Africa is well below that in the rest of the world and that this goes some way
to establishing the validity of the IQs for the countries of sub-Saharan Africa. Nevertheless to
meet this point more fully we have excluded the 15 African countries and rerun the calculations.
The results are that the correlation of IQ and per capita GNP 1998 falls from .706 to .625; the
correlation of IQ and real GDP per capita falls from .757 to .586; the correlation of IQ and
economic growth per capita GDP 1950-90 falls from .605 to .600; and the correlation of IQ and
economic growth per capita GNP 1976-98 falls from .643 to .513. Thus the exclusion of the 15
African countries reduces the correlations to some degree, as would be expected with the
reduction of variance in the reduced sample, but all four correlations remain substantial and
statistically significant at p<.001. We are forced to conclude that the exclusion of the 15
countries of sub-Saharan Africa makes no significant difference to the associations between
national IQs and economic growth.
It has been pointed out that correlation analysis does not establish causality because of the fact
that correlations merely measure covariation. Let us conseder what causality presupposes.
Manheim and Rich (1986: 21-22) say that it is justified to postulate causal relationships only
when four conditions are simultaneously met: First, the postulated cause and effect must
change together, or covary. Second, the cause must precede the effect. Third, we must be able
to identify a causal linkage between the supposed cause and effect. Fourth, the covariance of
the cause and effect phenomena must not be due to their simultaneous relationship to some
other third factor. We think that the relationship between national IQ and the measures of per
capita income and economic growth meets these requirements quite well. First, correlations
indicate that the postulated cause and effect change together. Second, because differences in
national IQs are partly genetic, they have certainly preceded contemporary differences in
economic conditions. Third, the causal linkage between the hypothesized cause and effect will
be discussed and explained in the next section. Fourth, it is highly improbable that the observed
covariance between cause and effect could be due to any third factor. This last requirement will
be discussed in greater detail in the next section. Consequently, we are quite confident that the
relationship is causal.
Although the correlations between national IQs and the measures of per capita income are high,
there are some countries which have much higher per capita incomes than would be expected
from their national IQs and other countries whose national per capita incomes are much lower
than expected. To examine these anomalies a regression analysis has been carried out to
disclose which countries deviate most from the regression line. This analysis is limited to the
regression of real GDP per capita 1998 on IQ. Real GDP per capita 1998 was selected for this
analysis because real GDP per capita (purchasing power parity) can be regarded as a more
valid measure of living standards than per capita GNP and because the correlation between
national IQs and real GDP per capita is stronger than the correlation between national IQs and
per capita GNP (see Table 2). The results of regression analysis are given in Table 3.
Table 2.
Inter correlations of National IQs, Two Measures of Per Capita National Income and Two
Measures of Economic Growth in 53-60 Countries
Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6
1 National IQ .706 .757 .605 .643
N=60 N=58 N=54 N=56
2 Per capita GNP 1998 .945 .402 .519
N=58 N=54 N=56
3 Real GDP per cap 1998 .411 .560
N=53 N=55
4 Growth per cap GDP 1950-9 .804
N=54
Table 3.
The Results of Regression Analysis of Real GDP Per Capita 1998 on IQ for 58 Countries
Country IQ Real GDP Per Residual Fitted
cap 1998 GDP-98 GDP-98
1 Argentina 96 12013 -3017 15030
2 Australia 99 22452 5799 16653
3 Belgium 99 23223 6570 16653
4 Brazil 87 6625 -3534 10159
5 Canada 97 23582 8011 15571
6 China 98 3105 -13007 16112
7 Congo (Brazzaville) 73 995 -1587 2582
8 Congo (Zaire) 68 822 946 -124
9 Croatia 90 8749 -5033 11782
10 Cuba 85 3967 -5109 9076
11 Czech Republic 98 12362 -3750 16112
12 Denmark 97 24218 8647 15571
13 Egypt 83 3041 -4953 7994
14 Ethiopia 67 574 1239 -665
15 Finland 98 20847 4735 16112
16 France 97 21175 5604 15571
17 Germany 103 22169 3351 18818
18 Ghana 62 1735 5106 -3371
19 Guinea 70 1782 824 958
20 Hong Kong 107 20763 -220 20983
21 India 82 2077 -5376 7453
22 Iran 84 5121 -3414 8535
23 Iraq 87 3197 -6962 10159
24 Ireland 87 21482 11323 10159
25 Israel 90 17301 5519 11782
26 Italy 103 20585 1767 18818
27 Japan 110 23257 651 22606
28 Kenya 72 980 -1061 2041
29 Korea, South 106 13478 -6964 20442
30 Malaysia 92 8137 -4728 12865
31 Mexico 88 7704 -2996 10700
32 Netherlands 100 22176 4982 17194
33 New Zealand 101 17288 -448 17736
34 Nigeria 69 795 378 417
35 Peru 76 4282 76 4206
36 Philippines 86 3555 -6063 9618
37 Poland 92 7619 -5246 12865
38 Portugal 91 14701 2377 12324
39 Puerto Rico 84 - - -
40 Qatar 78 20987 15699 5288
41 Romania 94 5648 -8299 13947
42 Russia 96 6450 -8580 15030
43 Sierra Leone 67 458 1123 -665
44 Singapore 103 24210 5392 18818
45 Slovakia 98 9699 -6413 16112
46 Slovenia 96 14293 -737 15030
47 South Africa 72 8488 6447 2041
48 Spain 96 16212 1182 15030
49 Sudan 72 1394 -647 2041
50 Switzerland 101 5161 7776 17736
51 Taiwan 104 - - -
52 Tanzania 74 480 -2643 3123
53 Thailand 91 5456 -6868 12324
54 Turkey 90 6422 -5360 11782
55 Uganda 73 1074 -1508 2582
56 United Kingdom 100 20336 3142 17194
57 United States 98 29605 13493 16112
58 Uruguay 96 8623 -6407 15030
59 Zambia 75 719 -2945 3664
60 Zimbabwe 70 2669 1711 958
Table 3 shows how much individual countries deviate from the regression line, which represents
the average relationship between national IQs and real GDP per capita in 1998. "Fitted GDP"
indicates the predicted value of real GDP per capita in 1998. If the correlation between IQs and
Real GDP per capita were perfect, all countries would be at the regression line and all residuals
would be zero. Because the correlation (0.757) is not perfect, all countries deviate to some
extent from the regression line. The residuals indicate the size and direction of the deviations.
Positive residuals indicate that nations have higher real GDP per capita than is predicted on the
basis of the average relationship between IQs and real GDP per capita, while negative residuals
indicate that their per capita incomes are lower than expected. The sum of "Residual GDP" and
"Fitted GDP" is always the same as the actual value of real GDP per capita given in Table 3.
There is no natural distinction between countries with large and small deviations. Because one
standard error of estimate is 5,583 real GDP per capita dollars in this regression analysis, it is
reasonable to regard as highly deviating cases all countries for which positive or negative
residuals are larger than 6,000. Positive residuals are large for eight countries: Belgium,
Canada, Denmark, Ireland, Qatar, South Africa, Switzerland and the United States. Negative
residuals are large for nine countries: China, Iraq, South Korea, the Philippines, Romania,
Russia, Slovakia, Thailand and Uruguay. We consider the explanations for these anomalies in
the discussion.
DISCUSSION
The hypotheses examined in this study have been that national per capita incomes and rates of
economic growth would be positively correlated with national IQs. These hypotheses have been
confirmed by strong correlations that are at a high level of statistical significance for both GNP
and GDP. If we adopt a one way causal model that national IQs are a determinant of national
per capita incomes and rates of economic growth, the results show that national IQ explains 57
percent of the variance of real GDP per capita 1998 and 50 percent of the variance of GNP per
capita 1998. National IQ also explains 37 percent of the variance in economic growth of per
capita GDP 1950-90 and 41 percent of the variance in economic growth of per capita GNP
1976-98.
There are two reasons why we consider that a causal effect of national IQ on per capita
incomes and rates of economic growth is the most reasonable theory to explain the correlations.
First, this theory is a corollary of an already established body of theory and data showing that IQ
is a determinant of income among individuals, the evidence for which has been reviewed in the
introduction. IQs measured in childhood are strong predictors of IQs in adolescence and these
are predictors of earnings in adulthood. The most reasonable interpretation of these
associations is that IQ is a determinant of earnings. From this it follows that groups with high
IQs would have higher average incomes than groups with low IQs because groups are
aggregates of individuals. This prediction has already been confirmed in the studies of the
positive relationship between IQs and per capita incomes among the American states and
among the regions of the British Isles, France and Spain, as noted in the introduction. The
positive relation between IQ and income is so well established that it can be designated a law,
of which the finding that national IQs are positively related to national per capita incomes is a
further instance.
Second, there is a straightforward explanation for the positive association between IQ and
incomes at both the individual and population level. The major reason for this association is that
people with high IQs can acquire complex skills that command high earnings and that cannot be
acquired by those with low IQs. Nations whose populations have high IQs tend to have efficient
economies at all levels from top and middle management through skilled and semi-skilled
workers. These nations are able to produce competitively goods and services for which there is
a strong international demand and for which there is therefore a high value, and that cannot be
produced by nations whose populations have low IQs. In addition, nations whose populations
have high IQs will have intelligent and efficient personnel in services and public sector
employment that contributes indirectly to the strength of the economy such as teachers,
doctors, scientists and a variety of public servants responsible for the running of telephones,
railroads, electricity supplies and other public utilities. Finally, nations whose populations have
high IQs are likely to have intelligent political leaders who manage their economies effectively.
Skilled economic management is required to produce the right conditions for economic growth,
such as keeping interest rates at the optimum level to produce full employment with minimum
inflation, maintaining competition, preventing the growth of monopolies, controlling crime and
corruption, and promoting education, literacy and numeracy and vocational training.
While we consider that a causal effect of national intelligence on per capita income and rates of
economic growth is the most reasonable model for an explanation of the data, there are two
other possible explanations that deserve consideration. The first of these is that there is no
direct causal relation between national IQs and per capita incomes and growth rates and the
correlation between them is due to some third factor affecting all three. Although this is a
theoretical possibility and needs to be mentioned, we do not think it is possible to formulate a
plausible theory of this kind.
Second, it might be argued that national per capita incomes are a cause of national differences
in IQs. This argument would state that rich nations provide advantageous environments to
nurture the intelligence of their children in so far as they are able to provide their children with
better nutrition, health care, education and whatever other environmental factors have an
impact on intelligence, the nature of which is discussed in Neisser (1998). Intelligence has
increased considerably in many nations during the twentieth century and there is little doubt that
these increases have been brought about by environmental improvements, which have
themselves occurred largely as a result of increases in per capita incomes that have enabled
people to give their children better nutrition, health care, education and the like. Such a theory
has some plausibility but it cannot explain the totality of the data. Countries like Japan, South
Korea, Taiwan and Singapore had high IQs in the 1960s when they had quite low per capita
incomes and the same is true of China today. Nevertheless, the model of national differences in
IQ as a major determinant of economic growth and per capita incomes should probably be
supplemented by the postulation of a small positive feedback in which national per capita
income has some impact on the population's IQ.
Our results are based on a sample of 60 nations out of approximately 185 nations of significant
size in the world. We believe that the sample can be regarded as relatively well representative
of the totality of nations because all categories of nations are well represented including the
economically developed "First World" market economies of North America, Western Europe,
Australia and New Zealand; the "Second World" former communist nations of Russia and
Eastern Europe; the "Third World" economically developing but impoverished nations of South
Asia, sub-Saharan Africa and the Caribbean; and the residual categories of Latin America and
East Asia. If the representativeness of our sample is accepted, our results indicate that slightly
over half the variance in national per capita income in the contemporary world is attributable to
national differences in IQ. However, it should be noted that correlations are somewhat lower in
the total group of 185 countries (see Lynn and Vanhanen, 2002). The difference in correlations
implies that this sample of 60 nations is probably slightly biased.
The regression analysis suggests that a major additional factor is the economic form of
organisation consisting of whether countries have market or socialist economies. The countries
that have the largest positive residuals and therefore have higher per capita income than would
be predicted from their IQs are Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Ireland, Israel,
Qatar, Singapore, South Africa, Switzerland and the United States. With the exception of Qatar
and South Africa, all of these are technologically highly developed market economy countries
and their higher than predicted per capita incomes can be attributed principally to this form of
economic organisation. Qatar's exceptionally high level of per capita national income is
principally due to its oil production industries. South Africa's much higher than expected level of
per capita income should probably be attributed principally to the cognitive skills of its European
minority who comprise 14 per cent of the population.
The countries that have the largest negative residuals are China, Iraq, South Korea, the
Philippines, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Thailand and Uruguay. Four of these countries (China,
Romania, Russia and Slovakia) are present or former socialist countries whose economic
development has been hampered by their socialist economic and political systems. After the
collapse of the Soviet communist systems in 1991 and the introduction of market economies in
these countries and in China, the prospects for rapid economic development for these countries
are good, although it takes time to establish effective market economies. Of the remaining five
countries with large negative residuals, Iraq's low level of per capita national income is due
principally to the destruction inflicted in 1990 war and the UN sanctions imposed in 1990. South
Korea's Real GDP per capita is also considerably lower than expected on the basis of the
country's exceptionally high level of national IQ (106). The principal explanation for this is
probably that South Korea had a very low per capita income at the end of World War Two as a
result of military defeat and occupation by the Japanese and that it has not yet had sufficient
time to achieve the predicted level of per capita income, although economic growth in South
Korea since 1950 has been extremely high (see Appendix 2). The Asian economic crisis in
1998 may have increased the negative residuals of the Philippines and Thailand temporarily.
Economic growth in Uruguay has been strong since the 1970s, although the country has not yet
achieved the per capita income level expected on the basis of its relatively high national IQ.
Thus our general conclusion is that national differences in the wealth and poverty of nations in
the contemporary world can be explained first in terms of the intelligence levels of the
populations; secondly, to some extent, in terms of whether they operate market or socialist
economies; and thirdly by unique circumstances such as the possession of valuable natural
resources like oil in the case of Qatar and trade sanctions imposed on Iraq.
Table 4
IQs for 185 countries
National IQs Based on the Results of Intelligence Tests and Estimated National IQs
(marked by *) Based on the IQs of Neighbouring or Other Comparable Countries.
Country National IQ based on Comparison countries
arithmetic means.
1 Afghanistan 83* Iran 84, India 81
2 Albania 90* Croatia 90, Turkey 90
3 Algeria 84* Morocco 85, Egypt 83
4 Angola 69* Zambia 77, Zimbabwe 66, Congo (Z) 65
5 Antigua & Barbuda 75* Barbados 78, Jamaica 72
6 Argentina 96
7 Armenia 93* Turkey 90, Russia 96
8 Australia 98
9 Austria 102
10 Azerbaijan 87* Turkey 90, Iran 84
11 Bahamas 78* Barbados 78
12 Bahrain 83* Iraq 87, Qatar 78
13 Bangladesh 81* India 81
14 Barbados 78
15 Belarus 96* Russia 96
16 Belgium 100
17 Belize 83* Guatemala 79, Mexico 87
18 Benin 69* Ghana 71, Nigeria 67
19 Bhutan 78* Nepal 78
20 Bolivia 85* Ecuador 80, Peru 90
21 Botswana 72* Zambia 77, Zimbabwe 66
22 Brazil 87
23 Brunei 92* Malaysia 92
24 Bulgaria 93
25 Burkina Faso 66* Guinea 63, Sierra Leone 64, Ghana 71
26 Burma (Myanmar) 86* India 81, Thailand 91
27 Burundi 70* Congo (Z) 65, Tanzania 72, Uganda 73
28 Cambodia 89* Thailand 91, Philippines 86
29 Cameroon 70* Nigeria 67, Congo (Braz) 73
30 Canada 97
31 Cape Verde 78* Mixed population-see notes
32 Central African Rep. 68* Congo (B) 73, Congo (Z) 65, Nigeria 67
33 Chad 72* Sudan 72
34 Chile 93* Argentina 96, Peru 90
35 China 100
36 Colombia 88
37 Comoros 79* Mixed Negroid-Arab-Malay population - see notes
38 Congo (Braz) 73
39 Congo (Zaire) 65
40 Costa Rica 91* Argentina 96, Uruguay 96, Colombia 88, Puerto Rico 84
41 Côte d'Ivoire 71* Ghana 71
42 Croatia 90
43 Cuba 85
44 Cyprus 92* Greece 92
45 Czech Republic 97
46 Denmark 98
47 Djibouti 68* Sudan 72, Ethiopia 63
48 Dominica 75* Barbados 78, Jamaica 72
49 Dominican Republic 84* Mixed population, Puerto Rico 84
50 Ecuador 80
51 Egypt 83
52 El Salvador 84* Guatemala 79, Colombia 88
53 Equatorial Guinea 59
54 Eritrea 68* Sudan 72, Ethiopia 63
55 Estonia 97* Finland 97, Russia 96
56 Ethiopia 63
57 Fiji 84
58 Finland 97
59 France 98
60 Gabon 66* Congo (B) 73, Equatorial Guinea 59
61 Gambia 64* Sierra Leone 64, Guinea 63
62 Georgia 93* Russia 96, Turkey 90
63 Germany 102
64 Ghana 71
65 Greece 92
66 Grenada 75* Barbados 78, Jamaica 72
67 Guatemala 79
68 Guinea 63
69 Guinea-Bissau 63* Guinea 63
70 Guyana 84* Suriname 89, Barbados 78
71 Haiti 72* Jamaica 72
72 Honduras 84* Guatemala 79, Colombia 88
73 Hong Kong 107
74 Hungary 99
75 Iceland 98* Norway 98
76 India 81
77 Indonesia 89
78 Iran 84
79 Iraq 87
80 Ireland 93
81 Israel 94
82 Italy 102
83 Jamaica 72
84 Japan 105
85 Jordan 87* Iraq 87, Lebanon 86
86 Kazakhstan 93* Russia 96, Turkey 90
87 Kenya 72
88 Kiribati 84* Marshall Islands 84, Fiji 84
89 Korea, North 105* South Korea 106,Japan 105
90 Korea, South 106
91 Kuwait 83* Iraq 87, Qatar 78
92 Kyrgyzstan 87* Turkey 90, Iran 84
93 Laos 89* Thailand 91, Philippines 86
94 Latvia 97* Russia 96, Finland 97
95 Lebanon 86
96 Lesotho 72* Zambia 77, Zimbabwe 66
97 Liberia 64* Sierra Leone 64, Guinea 63
98 Libya 84* Morocco 85, Egypt 83
99 Lithuania 97* Russia 96, Finland 97
100 Luxembourg 101* Netherlands 102, Belgium 100
101 Macedonia 93* Bulgaria 93, Greece 92
102 Madagascar 79* Mixed Malay-Negroid population - see notes
103 Malawi 71* Congo (Z) 65, Tanzania 72, Zambia 77
104 Malaysia 92
105 Maldives 81* India 81
106 Mali 68* Guinea 63, Sudan 72
107 Malta 95* Italy 102, Spain 99, Morocco 85
108 Marshall Islands 84
109 Mauritania 73* Guinea 63, Morocco 85, Sudan 72
110 Mauritius 81* Mixed population-see notes
111 Mexico 87
112 Micronesia 84* Marshall Islands 84
113 Moldova 95* Romania 94, Russia 96
114 Mongolia 98* Russia 96, China 100
115 Morocco 85
116 Mosambique 72* Tanzania 72, Zimbabwe 66, Zambia 77
117 Namibia 72* Zambia 77, Zimbabwe 66
118 Nepal 78
119 Netherlands 102
120 New Zealand 100
121 Nicaragua 84* Guatemala 79, Colombia 88
122 Niger 67* Nigeria 67
123 Nigeria 67
124 Norway 98
125 Oman 83* Iraq 87, Qatar 78
126 Pakistan 81* India 81
127 Panama 84* Colombia 88, Ecuador 80
128 Papua New Guinea 84* Marshall Islands 84, Fiji 84
129 Paraguay 85* Ecuador 80, Peru 90
130 Peru 90
131 Philippines 86
132 Poland 99
133 Portugal 95
134 Puerto Rico 84
135 Qatar 78
136 Romania 94
137 Russia 96
138 Rwanda 70* Congo (Z) 65, Tanzania 72, Uganda 73
139 Samoa (Western) 87
140 Sao Tome/Principe 59* Equatorial Guinea 59
141 Saudi Arabia 83* Iraq 87, Qatar 78
142 Senegal 64* Sierra Leone 64, Guinea 63
143 Seychelles 81* Mixed population, India 81
144 Sierra Leone 64
145 Singapore 100
146 Slovakia 96
147 Slovenia 95
148 Solomon Islands 84* Marshall Islands 84, Fiji 84
149 Somalia 68* Ethiopia 63, Kenya 72
150 South Africa 72 See notes
151 Spain 99
152 Sri Lanka 81* India 81
153 St. Kitts & Nevis 75* Barbados 78, Jamaica 72
154 St. Lucia 75* Barbados 78, Jamaica 72
155 St.Vincent/Grenadines 75* Barbados 78, Jamaica 72
156 Sudan 72
157 Suriname 89
158 Swaziland 72* Zambia 77, Zimbabwe 66
159 Sweden 101
160 Switzerland 101
161 Syria 87* Iraq 87, Lebanon 86
162 Taiwan 104
163 Tajikistan 87* Turkey 90, Iran 84
164 Tanzania 72
165 Thailand 91
166 Togo 69* Ghana 71, Nigeria 67
167 Tonga 87
168 Trinidad & Tobago 80* 78, Jamaica 72 Suriname 89, Barbados
169 Tunisia 84* Morocco 85, Egypt 83
170 Turkey 90
171 Turkmenistan 87* Turkey 90, Iran 84
172 Uganda 73
173 Ukraine 96* Russia 96
174 United Arab Emirates 83* Iraq 87, Qatar 78
175 United Kingdom 100
176 United States 98
177 Uruguay 96
178 Uzbekistan 87* Turkey 90, Iran 84
179 Vanuatu 84* Marshall Islands 84, Fiji 84
180 Venezuela 88* Colombia 88
181 Vietnam 96* China 100, Thailand 91
182 Yemen 83* Iraq 87, Qatar 78
183 Yugoslavia 93* Croatia 90, Slovenia 95
184 Zambia 77
185 Zimbabwe 66
See also Publications
IQ and the Wealth of Nations
(Co-author Tatu Vanhanen, Univerisity of Helsinki) Westport, CT: Praeger, 2002.
APPENDIX 1
Data on National IQs Obtained from the Colored and Standard Progressive Matrices
Country Age Test Number IQ Reference
Argentina 5-11 CPM 420 98 Raven et al., 1998
Australia 5-10 CPM 700 98 Raven et al., 1995
Australia 8-17 SMP 4,000 99 Raven et al., 1996
Belgium 7-13 SMP 944 99 Goosens, 1952
Brazil 14 SMP 160 88 Natalicio, 1968
Brazil 7-11 CPM 505 84 Angelini et al., 1988
Brazil 5-11 CPM 1,131 90 Angelini wt al., 1988
Brazil 5-11 CPM 1,547 85 Angelini et al., 1988
Britain 6-15 SPM 3,258 100 Raven, 1981
Canada 7-12 SPM 313 97 Raven et al., 1996
China 6-79 SPM 5,108 98 Raven et al., 1996
Congo (Br) Adults SPM 320 73 Ombredane et al., 1952
Congo (Br) 13 SPM 88 72 Nkaya et al., 1994
Congo (Zaire) 10-15 SPM 222 68 Laroche, 1959
Croatia 13-16 SPM 299 90 Sorokin, 1954
Cuba 12-18 SMP 1,144 85 Alonso, 1974
Czech Rep. 5-11 CPM 832 98 Raven et al., 1996
Denmark 12 SPM 628 97 Vejleskov, 1968
Egypt 6-12 SPM 129 83 Ahmed, 1989
Ethiopia 15-16 SPM 250 67 Lynn, 1994
Finland 7 SPM 755 98 Kyostio, 1972
France 6-9 CPM 618 97 Bourdier, 1964
Germany 11-15 SPM 2,068 105 Raven, 1981
Germany 6-10 CPM 3,607 101 Raven et al., 1995
Ghana 15 CPM 1,639 62 Glewwe & Jacoby, 1992
Guinea 20 SPM 1,144 70 Faverge et al., 1962
Hong Kong 3-13 SPM 13,822 103 Lynn et al., 1988
Hong Kong 6-15 SPM 4,500 110 Lynn et al., 1988
Hong Kong 6 CPM 4,858 109 Chan & Lynn, 1989
India 9-15 CPM 5,607 81 Sinha, 1968
India 5-10 CPM 1,050 82 Rao & Reddy, 1968
India 11-15 SPM 569 82 Raven et al., 1996
Iran 15 SPM 627 84 Valentine, 1957
Iraq 14-17 SPM 204 87 Abul-Hubb, 1972
Iraq 18-35 SPM 1,185 85 Abul-Hubb, 1972
Ireland 6-13 SPM 3,466 87 Raven, 1981
Israel 9-15 SPM 250 90 Lynn, 1994
Italy 11-16 SPM 2,432 103 Tesi & Young, 1962
Japan 9 SPM 444 110 Shigehisa & Lynn, 1991
Kenya Adults CPM 205 69 Boissiere et al., 1985
Kenya 6-10 CPM 1,222 75 Costenbader et al., 2000
Korea, South 9 SPM 107 106 Lynn & Song, 1994
Malaysia 7-12 SPM 5,412 92 Chaim, 1994
Mexico 6-11 CPM 597 84 Raven, 1986
Mexico 6-11 CPM 434 95 Raven, 1986
Mexico 9-12 SPM 404 84 Raven, 1986
Netherlands 4-10 CPM 1,920 99 Raven et al., 1995
Netherlands 6-12 SPM 4,032 101 Raven et al., 1996
New Zealand 8-17 SPM 2,635 101 Reid & Gilmore, 1989
Nigeria Adults SPM 86 69 Wober, 1969
Nigeria 6-13 CPM 375 69 Fahrmeier, 1975
Peru 8-11 CPM 4,382 76 Raven et al., 1995
Philippines 12-13 SPM 203 86 Flores & Evans, 1972
Poland 6-15 SPM 4,006 92 Jarorowska et al., 1991
Portugal 6-12 CPM 807 91 Simoes, 1989
Puerto Rico 5-11 CPM 2,400 83 Raven et al., 1995
Puerto Rico 8-15 SPM 2,911 84 Raven & Court, 1989
Qatar 12 SPM 273 78 Bart et al., 1987
Romania 6-10 CPM 300 94 Zahirnic et al., 1974
Russia 14 SPM 432 96 Raven, 1988
Sierra Leone Adults CPM 60 67 Berry, 1966
Singapore 13 SPM 147 103 Lynn, 1977
Slovak Rep. 5-11 CPM 832 98 Raven et al., 1995
Slovenia 8-18 SPM 1,556 95 Roben, 1999
South Africa 16 SPM 3,993 72 Owen, 1992
Spain 4-9 CPM 1,189 96 Raven et al., 1995
Switzerland 6-10 CPM 408 99 Raven et al., 1995
Switzerland 6-10 CPM 167 102 Raven et al., 1995
Sudan 8-12 SPM 148 72 Ahmed, 1989
Taiwan 6-7 CPM 43,825 103 Hsu, 1976
Thailand 8-10 CPM 1,358 91 Pollitt et al., 1989
Taiwan 9-12 SPM 2,496 105 Lynn, 1997
Tanzania 17 SPM 2,959 78 Klingelhofer, 1967
Tanzania Adults CPM 179 69 Boissiere et al., 1985
Turkey 6-15 SPM 2,277 90 Sahin & Duzen, 1994
United States 18-70 SPM 625 98 Raven et al., 1996
Uganda 11 CPM 2,019 73 Heyneman et al., 1980
Uruguay 12-44 SPM 1,634 96 Risso, 1961
Zambia 13 SPM 894 75 MacArthur et al., 1964
Zimbabwe 12-14 SPM 204 70 Zindi, 1994
APPENDIX 2
Data for GNP Per Capita in 1998 and Real GDP Per Capita (PPP) in 1998 in US Dollars and
for Economic Growth of GDP Per Capita over the Period 1950-90 and of GNP Per Capita
over the Period 1976-98 for 60 Countries.
Country Per capita Real GDP per Growth per Growth per
GNP 1998 capita 1998 capita GDP capita GNP
1950-90 % 1976-98 %
1 Argentina 8,970 12,013 65.3 478.7
2 Australia 20,300 22,452 127.4 232.8
3 Belgium 25,380 23,223 214.4 274.3
4 Brazil 4,570 6,625 187,6 300.9
5 Canada 20,020 23,582 178.1 166.6
6 China 750 3,105 339.7 82.9
7 Congo (Brazz.) 690 995 97.8 32.7
8 Congo (Zaire) 110 822 -28.0 -21.4
9 Croatia 4,520 6,749 - -
10 Cuba 3,0001 3,967 -17.8 248.8
11 Czech Republic 5,040 12,362 141.8 31.3
12 Denmark 32,7672 24,218 168.6 346.4
13 Egypt 1,290 3,041 292.6 360.7
14 Ethiopia 100 574 26.4 0.0
15 Finland 24,110 20,847 301.9 329.0
16 France 24,940 21,175 240.5 280.8
17 Germany 25,850 22,169 336.5 250.3
18 Ghana 390 1,735 -19.0 -32.8
19 Guinea 540 1,782 72.3 260.0
20 Hong Kong 21,6503 20,763 - 612.2
21 India 430 2,077 120.4 186.7
22 Iran 1,770 5,121 93.6 -8.3
23 Iraq 2,0001 3,197 79.9 43.9
24 Ireland 18,340 21,482 216.2 616.4
25 Israel 15,940 17,301 311.7 306.6
26 Italy 20,250 20,585 365,7 563.9
27 Japan 32,380 23,257 890.3 559.6
28 Kenya 330 980 77.2 37.5
29 Korea, South 7,970 13,478 924.8 1089.6
30 Malaysia 3,600 8,137 232.4 318.6
31 Mexico 3,970 7,704 139.7 264.2
32 Netherlands 24,760 22,176 132.2 299.4
33 New Zealand 14,700 17,288 64.7 245.9
34 Nigeria 300 795 104.4 -21.1
35 Peru 2,460 4,282 32.6 207.5
36 Philippines 1,050 3,555 77.9 156.1
37 Poland 3,900 7,619 108.9 36.4
38 Portugal 10,690 14,701 401.2 532.5
39 Puerto Rico 7,010 - - -
40 Qatar 7,4294 20,987 -46.2 77.9
41 Romania 1,390 5,648 192.7 -4.1
42 Russia (USSR) 2,300 6,450 142.4 -16.7
43 Sierra Leone 140 458 42.6 -30.0
44 Singapore 30,060 24,210 619.5 1013.3
45 Slovakia 3,700 9,699 - -
46 Slovenia 9,760 14,293 - -
47 South Africa 2,880 8,488 65.2 114.9
48 Spain 14,080 16,212 407.7 77.2
49 Sudan 290 1,394 10.7 0.0
50 Switzerland 32,7672 25,512 142.3 351.4
51 Taiwan 13,2335 - 1019.7 1136.7
52 Tanzania 210 480 40.3 16.7
53 Thailand 2,200 5,456 - 478.9
54 Turkey 3,160 6,422 392.1 219.2
55 Uganda 320 1,074 228.2 33.3
56 United Kingdom 21,400 20,336 138.1 432.3
57 United States 29,340 29,605 128.4 271.9
58 Uruguay 6,180 8,623 31.3 344.6
59 Zambia 330 719 11.6 -25.0
60 Zimbabwe 610 2,669 55.6 10.9
Sources:
GNP per capita in 1998:
World Development Report 1999/2000, Table a and Table 1a, if not otherwise noted.
1. Estimation.
2. In the statistical analysis, the highest number is limited to 32,767.
3. Eccleston, Dawson, and McNamara 1998, p. 221, year 1994.
4. World Development Report 1998/99, Table 1, year 1997.
5. The Far East and Australasia 1999, p. 322, year 1997.
Real GDP per capita in 1998:
Human Development Report 2000, Table 1.
Growth per capita GDP 1950-90 percent:
All data on per capita GDP 1950 and 1990 are from Maddison, 1995.
Growth per capita GNP 1976-98 percent:
All data on per capita GNP 1976 are from the World Bank's World Development Report 1978
and nearly all data on per capita GNP 1998 from World Development Report 1999/2000.
REFERENCES
Abul-Hubb, D. (1972) Application of Progressive Matrices in Iraq. In L.J. Cronbach and P.J. Drenth (eds)
Mental Tests and Cultural Adaptation. The Hague: Mouton.
Ahmed, R.A. (1989) The development of number, space, quantity and reasoning concepts in Sudanese
schoolchildren. In L.L. Adler (ed.) Cross Cultural Research in Human Development. Westport, CT:
Praeger.
Alonso, O.S. (1974) Raven, g factor, age and school level. Havana Hospital Psiquiatrico Revista, 14, 60-
77.
Angelini, A.L., Alves, I.C., Custodio, E.M. and Duarte, W.F. (1988) Manual Matrizes Progressivas
Coloridas. Sao Paulo: Casa do Psicologo.
Baker, D.P. and Jones, D.P. (1993) Creating gender equality; cross national gender stratification and
mathematical performance. Sociology of Education, 66, 91-103.
Bart, W., Kamal, A. and Lane, J.F. (1987) The development of proportional reasoning in Qatar. Journal
of Genetic Psychology, 148, 95-103.
Bates, R.H. (1998) Governments and Agricultural Markets in Africa. In M.A. Seligson and J.T. Pass%7Å„-
Smith (eds) Development and Underdevelopment: The Political Economy of Global Inequality.
Boulder and London: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Benton, A.E., Mullis, I.V., Martin, M.O., Gonzalez, E.J., Kelly, D.L. and Smith, T.A. (1996a)
Mathematical Achievement in the Middle School Years. Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA:
TIMSS.
Benton, A.E., Mullis, I.V., Martin, M.O., Gonzalez, E.J., Kelly, D.L. and Smith, T.A. (1996b) Science
Achievement in the Middle School Years. Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA: TIMSS.
Berry, J.W. (1966) Temne and Eskimo perceptual skills. International Journal of Psychology, 1, 207-229.
Boben, D. (1999) Slovene Standardization of Raven's Progressive Matrices. Ljubljana: Center za
Psihodiagnostica.
Boissiere, M, Knight, J.B. and Sabot, R.H. (1985) Earnings, schooling, ability and cognitive skills.
American Economic Review, 75, 1016-1030.
Bourdier, G.(1964) Utilisation et nouvel etalonnage du P.M. 47. Bulletin de Psychologie, 235, 39-41.
Brown, W.W. and Reynolds, M.O. (1975) A model of IQ, occupation and earnings. American Economic
Review, 65, 1002-1007.
Chaim, H.H. (1994) Is the Raven Progressive Matrices valid for Malaysians? Unpublished.
Chan, J. and Lynn, R. (1989) The intelligence of six year olds in Hong Kong. Journal of Biosocial
Science, 21, 461-464.
Costenbader, V. and Ngari, S.M. (2000) A Kenya standardisation of the Coloured Progressive Matrices.
Unpublished.
Court, J.H. (1980) ResearchersÕ Bibliography for RavenÕs Progressive Matrices and Mill Hill
Vocabulary Scales. Adelaide: Flinders University.
Court, J.H. and Raven, J (1995) Normative, Reliability and Validity Studies: References. Oxford: Oxford
Psychologists Press.
Davenport, K.S. and Remmers, H.H. (1950) Factors in state characteristics related to average A-12 V-12
test scores. Journal of Educational Psychology, 41, 110-115.
Diamond, J. (1998) Guns, Germs and Steel: A Short History of Everybody for the Last 13,000 Years.
London: Vintage.
Duncan, O.D., Featherman, D.L. and Duncan, B. (1972) Socioeconomic Background and Achievement.
New York: Seminar Press.
Eccleston, B., Dawson, M. and McNamara, D. (eds) 1998) The Asia-Pacific Profile. London and New
York: Routledge.
Fahrmeier, E.D. (1975) The effect of school attendance on intellectual development in Northern Nigeria.
Child Development, 46, 281-285.
The Far East and Australasia 1999 (1999) London: Europa Publications Limited.
Faverge, J.M. and Falmagne, J.C. (1962) On the interpretation of data in intercultural psychology.
Psychologia Africana, 9, 22-96.
Flores, M.B. and Evans, G.T. (1972) Some differences in cognitive abilities between selected Canadian
and Filipino students. Multivariate Behavioral Research, 7, 175-191.
Frank, A.G. (1996) The Underdevelopment of Development. In Singh C. Chew and R. A. Denemark
(eds) The Underdevlopment of Development. Essays in Honor of Andre Gunder Frank. Thousands
Oaks: Sage Publications.
Frank, A.G. (2000) The Development of Underdevelopment (1969). In T. Roberts and A. Hite (eds) From
Modernization to Globalization. Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell Publishers.
Gardner, H.S. (1998) Comparative Economic Systems. Second Edition. Forth Worth Philadelphia: The
Dryden Press.
Glewwe, P and Jaccoby, H. (1992) Estimating the Determinants of Cognitive Achievement in Low
Income Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Goosens, G. (1952) Etalonnage du Matrix 1947 de J.C.Raven. Revue Belge de Psychologie et de
Pedagogie, 14, 74-80.
Heyneman, S.P. and Jamison, D.T. (1980) Student learning in Uganda. Comparative Education Review,
24, 207-220.
Hoyos, C. and Littlejohns, M. (2000) Annan draws up road map to guide UN. Financial Times, 4 April,
16.
Hsu, C. (1976) The learning potential of first graders in Taipei city as measured by RavenÕs Coloured
Progressive Matrices. Acta Pediatrica Sinica, 17, 262-274.
Human Development Report 1997 (1997) Published for the United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP). New York: Oxford University Press.
Human Development Report 1999 (1999) Published for the United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP). New York: Oxford University Press.
Human Development Report 2000 (2000) Published for the United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP). New York: Oxford University Press.
Hunter, J.E. and Hunter, R.F. (1984) Validity and utility of alternative predictors of job performance.
Psychological Bulletin, 96, 72-98.
IEA (1998) Science achievement in Seventeen Countries. Oxford: Pergamon.
Jaworowska, A. and Szustrowa, T. (1991) Podrecznik Do Testu Matryc Ravena. Warsaw: Pracownia
Testow Psychologicznych.
Jencks, S. (1972) Inequality. London: Penguin.
Jencks, C. (1979) Who Gets Ahead? The Determinants of Economic Success in America. New York:
Basic Books.
Jensen, A.R. (1998) The g Factor. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Kamarck, Andrew M. (1976) The Tropics and Economic Dvelopment: A Provocative Inquiry into the
Poverty of Nations. Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Klingelhofer, E.L. (1967) Performance of Tanzanian secondary school pupils on the Raven Standard
Progressive Matrices test. Journal of Social Psychology, 72, 205-215.
Kyostio, O.K. (1972) Divergence among school beginners caused by different cultural influences. In L.J.
Cronbach and P.J. Drenth (eds) Mental Tests and Cultural Adaptation. The Hague: Mouton.
Landes, D.S. (1998) The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor.
New York: W.W. Norton & Company.
Laroche, J.L. (1959) Effets de repetition du Matrix 38 sur les resultats dIenfants Katangais. Bulletin du
Centre dIEtudes et Recherches Psychotechniques, 1, 85-99.
Li, C.C. (1975) Path Analysis: A Primer. Pacific Grove, CA: Boxwood Press.
Lynn, R. (1977) The intelligence of the Chinese and Malays in Singapore. Mankind Quarterly, 18, 125-
128.
Lynn, R. (1979) The social ecology of intelligence in the British Isles. British Journal of Social and
Clinical Psychology, 18, 1-12.
Lynn, R. (1980) The social ecology of intelligence in France. British Journal of Social and Clinical
Psychology, 19, 325-331.
Lynn, R. (1981) The social ecology of intelligence in the British Isles, France and Spain. In
M.P.Friedman, J.P.Das and N. O'Connor (eds) Intelligence and Learning. New York: Plenum.
Lynn, R. (1991) Race differences in intelligence: a global perspective. Mankind Quarterly, 31, 255-294.
Lynn, R. (1994) The intelligence of Ethiopian immigrant and Israeli adolescents. International Journal of
Psychology, 29, 55-56.
Lynn, R. (1997) Intelligence in Taiwan. Personality and Individual Differences, 22, 585-586.
Lynn, R and Hampson, S.L. (1986) The rise of national intelligence: evidence from Britain, Japan and the
USA. Personality and Individual Differences, 7, 23-332.
Lynn, R., Pagliari, C. and Chan, J. (1988) Intelligence in Hong Kong measured for SpearmanÕs g and the
visuospatial and verbal primaries. Intelligence, 12, 423-433.
Lynn, R. and Song, M.J. (1994) General intelligence, visuospatial and verbal abilities of Korean children.
Personality and Individual Differences, 16, 363-364.
Lynn, R., and Vanhanen, T. (2002) IQ and the Wealth of Nations. Westport, Connecticut: Praeger.
MacArthur, R.S., Irvine, S.H. and Brimble, A.R. (1964) The Northern Rhodesia Mental Ability Survey.
Lusaka: Rhodes Livingstone Institute.
McClelland, D.C. (1976) The Achieving Society. Princeton: Van Nostrand.
Maddison, A. (1995) Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992. Paris: Development Centre of the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Mannheim, J. B., Rich, R. C. (1986) Empirical Political Analysis: Research Methods in Political Science.
Second edition. New York and London: Longman.
Martin, M.O. (1997) Science Achievement in the Primary School Years. Boston College, Chestnut Hill,
MA: TIMSS.
Mullis, I.V.S. (1997) Mathematics Achievement in the Primary School Years. Boston College, Chestnut
Hill, MA: TIMSS.
The Middle East and North Africa 1998 (1998). London: Europa Publications Limited.
Montesquieu (1961[1748]) De l'Esprit des Lois. Paris: Editions Garnier Fr%7Å„res.
Murray, C. (1998) Income Inequality and IQ. Washington, DC: AEI Press.
Natalicio, L. (1968) Aptidatao general, status social e sexo: um estudio de adolescentes Brasilieros e
norte-Americanos. Revista Interamericana de Psicologia, 2, 25-34.
Neisser, U. (1998) The Rising Curve. Washington, DC: American Psychological Association.
Nkaya, H.N., Huteau, M and Bonnet, J-P. (1994) Retest effect on cognitive performance on the Raven
Matrices in France and in the Congo. Perceptual and Motor Skills, 78, 503-510.
Ombredane, A., Robaye, F. and Robaye, E. (1952) Analyse des resultats d'une application experimentale
du matrix 38 a 485 noirs Baluba. Bulletin Centre dIEtudes et Researches Psychotechniques, 7, 235-
255.
Owen, K. (1992) The suitability of Raven's Progressive Matrices for various groups in South Africa.
Personality and Individual Differences, 13, 149-159.
Pollitt, E., Hathirat, P., Kotchabhakdi, N., Missell, L. and Valyasevi, A. (1989) Iron deficiency and
educational achievement in Thailand. American Journal of Clinical Nutrition, 50, 687-697.
Ramsay, F.J. (1999) Global Studies: Africa. Eight Edition. Sluice Dock, Guilford, Connecticut:
Dushkin/McGraw-Hill.
Rao, S.N. and Reddy, I.K. (1968) Development of norms for RavenÕs Coloured Progressive Matrices on
elementary school children. Psychological Studies, 13, 105-107.
Raven, J. (1981) Irish and British Standardisations. Oxford: Oxford Psychologists Press.
Raven, J (1986) Manual for RavenÕs Progressive Matrices and Vocabulary Scales. London: Lewis.
Raven, J. (1998) Manual for RavenÕs Progressive Matrices. Oxford: Oxford Psychologists Press.
Raven, J. and Court, J.H. (1989) Manual for RavenÕs Progressive Matrices and Vocabulary Scales.
London: Lewis.
Raven, J.C., Court, J.H. and Raven, J. (1995) Coloured Progressive Matrices. Oxford: Oxford
Psychologists Press.
Raven, J.C., Court, J.H. and Raven, J. (1996) Standard Progressive Matrices. Oxford: Oxford
Psychologists Press.
Raven, J.C., Court, J.H. and Raven, J. (1999) Standard Progressive Matrices. Oxford: Oxford
Pychologists Press.
Raven, J., Raven, J.C. and Court, J.H. (1998) Coloured Progressive Matrices. Oxford: Oxford
Psychologists Press.
Rimoldi, H.J. (1948) A note on RavenÕs Progressive Matrices Test. Educational and Psychological
Measurement, 8, 347-352.
Reid, N. and Gilmore, A. (1989) The RavenÕs Standard Progressive Matrices in New Zealand.
Psychological Test Bulletin, 2, 25-35.
Risso, W.L. (1961) El test de Matrice Progressivas y el test Domino. Proceedings of the 1961 Conference
of the Psychological Society of Uruguay.
Sahin, N. and Duzen, E. (1994) Turkish standardisation of Raven's SPM. Proceedings of the 23rd
International Congress of Applied Psychology, Madrid.
Santos, T. dos (1993) The Structure of Dependence. In M. A. Seligson and J. T. Pass%7Å„-Smith (eds)
Development and Underdevelopment. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Santos, T. dos (1996) Latin American Underdevelopment: Past, Present, and Future. In Singh C. Chew
and R. A. Denemark (eds) The Underdevelopment of Development. Essays in Honor of Andre
Gunder Frank. Thousands Oaks: Sage Publications.
Seligson, M.A. and Pass%7Å„-Smith, J.T. (eds) (1998) Development and Underdevelopment. The Political
Economy of Global Inequality. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Shigehisa, T. and Lynn, R. (1991) Reaction times and intelligence in Japanese children. International
Journal of Psychology, 26, 195-202.
Simoes, M.M.R. (1989) Un estudo exploratorio com o teste das matrizes progressivas de Raven para
criancas. Proceedings of the Congress of Psychology, Lisbon.
Sinha, U.(1968) The use of RavenÕs Progressive Matrices in India. Indian Educational Review, 3, 75-88.
Smith, A. (1976[1776]) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations. Edited by
Edwin Cannan. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Sorokin, B. (1954) Standardisation of the Progressive Matrices test. Unpublished Report.
Tesi, G. and Bourtourline Young, H. (1962) A standardisation of RavenÕs Progressive Matrices. Archive
de Psicologia Neurologia e Pscichologia, 5, 455-464.
Valentine, M. (1959) Psychometric testing in Iran. Journal of Mental Science, 105, 93-107.
Valenzuela, J.S. and Valenzuelas, A. (1998) Modernization and dependency: Alternataive Perspectives in
the Study of Latin American Underdevelopment. In M.A. Seligson and J.T. Pass%7Å„-Smith (eds)
Development and Underdevelopment. The Political Economy of Global Inequality. Boulder: Lynne
Rienner Publishers.
Vejleskov, H. (1968) An analysis of Raven Matrix responses in fifth grade children. Scandinavian
Journal of Psychology, 9, 177-186.
Wallerstein, I. (1998) The Present State of the Debate on World Inequality. In M.A. Seligson and J.T.
Pass%7Å„-Smith (eds) Development and Underdevelopment. The Political Economy of Global
Inequality. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Weber, M. (1970[1930]) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (1904). Translated by T.
Parsons. New York: Schriber.
Weede, E. (1998) Why People Stay Poor Elsewhere, in M.A. Seligson and J.T. Pass%7Å„-Smith (eds)
Development and Underdevelopment: The Political Economy of Global Inequality. Boulder and
London: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Wober, M. (1969) The meaning and stability of RavenÕs matrices test among Africans. International
Journal of Psychology, 4, 229-235.
World Bank (1978) World Development Report 1978. Published for the World Bank. New York: Oxford
University Press.
World Bank (1999) World Development Report 1998/1999. Published for the World Bank. New York:
Oxford University Press.
World Bank (2000) World Development Report 1999/2000: Entering the 21st Century. Published for the
World Bank. New York: Oxford University Press.
Zahirnic, C., Girboveanu, M., Onofrei, A., Turcu, A., Voicu, C. Voicu, M and Visan, O.M. (1974)
Etolonarea matricelor progressive colorate Raven. Revista de Psihologie, 20, 313-321.
Zindi, F. (1994) Differences in psychometric performance. The Psychologist, 7, 549-552.
Estimation of Missing National IQs
We want to extend the analysis to the further 104 countries with populations of more than 50,000 for
which we have not been able to find IQ data. For these 104 countries we have estimated the IQs. Two
principles have been adopted for making the estimates of national IQs for those countries for which data
are lacking. First, it is assumed that national IQs which are unknown will be closely similar to those in
neighboring countries whose IQs are known. It can be seen from the results set out in Table 6.1 that
neighboring countries normally have closely similar IQs. Thus, for instance, the IQ in both Germany and
the Netherlands is 102; the IQ in Japan is 105 and the IQ in South Korea is 106; the IQ in Argentina and
in Uruguay is 96; the IQ in Uganda is 73 and in Kenya 72; and so forth. It is therefore assumed that where
national IQs are unknown, they will be closely similar to those in neighboring countries. We have
therefore taken the most appropriate neighboring countries and used their IQs to assign IQs to countries
whose IQs are unknown. Where there are two or more appropriate neighboring countries, the IQs of these
are averaged to obtain an estimated IQ for the country whose IQ is unknown. Thus, for example, to
estimate an IQ for Afghanistan, we have averaged the IQs of neighboring India (81) and Iran (84) to give
an IQ of 83. Averages with decimal points have been rounded towards 100.
A second principle for the estimation of national IQs has been used for several countries which are
racially mixed and for which there is no similar neighboring country. In these cases we have assigned IQs
to the racial groups on the basis of the known IQs of these groups in neighboring countries. For example,
Cape Verde, the archipelago off the coast of Senegal, has a population which is 1 percent white, 28
percent black and 71 percent mixed black-white (Philip's, 1996). On the basis of the IQs of these groups
in South Africa, it is assumed that the whites have an IQ of 94, the blacks of 66 and the mixed of 82, the
IQ of South African coloreds (see Appendix 1). Weighting these figures by the percentages in the
population gives an IQ of 78.
The racially mixed population of the Comoros consists of African (black), Arab and Malagasy elements.
It is not any longer possible to separate clearly different racial groups. Because the racial composition of
the population is comparable with Madagascar's population, we estimate its national IQ to be 79, the same
as in Madagascar. The Malayo-Polynesians and Negroids constitute the principal elements in the racially
mixed population of Madagascar. The contribution of each of them may be approximately equal.
Therefore, it is reasonable to estimate the national IQ for Madagascar on the basis of the Philippines (86)
and Tanzania (72), which gives an IQ of 79 for Madagascar. For Mauritius, the population consists of 68
percent Indians, 27 percent Creole (black-white hybrids), 3 percent Chinese and 1 percent whites. It is
assumed that the IQs are 81 for the Indians (as in India), 82 for the Creoles (as for South African
coloreds), 100 for the Chinese (as in China) and 94 for the whites (as for the whites in South Africa).
Weighting these figures by the percentages in the population gives an IQ of 81.
Table 4 shows these estimated IQs and the comparison countries on which they are based, together with
measured IQs. We should emphasize that these data on national IQs are estimates and that they certainly
contain errors, but we assume that the margin of error is relatively small in nearly all cases.


Wyszukiwarka

Podobne podstrony:
Beyerl P The Symbols And Magick of Tarot
Ecology and behaviour of the tarantulas
Ciaran Brady The Chief Governors; The Rise and Fall of Reform Government in Tudor Ireland 1536 158
Introducing the ICCNSSA Standard for Design and Construction of Storm Shelters
Bertalanffy The History and Status of General Systems Theory
Herbs Of The Field And Herbs Of The Garden In Byzantine Medicinal Pharmacy
Cytotoxicity and Modes of Action of the Methanol Extracts
anatomy and physiology of the cardiovascular system
The role and significance of extracellular polymers in activated sludge
Advances in the Detection and Diag of Oral Precancerous, Cancerous Lesions [jnl article] J Kalmar
Napoleon Hill The 17 Universal Principles of Success and Achievement
Pirenne Delforge V , Pausanias Cults of the Gods and Representation of the Divine
INTRODUCTION OF THE PERSONAL?TA PRIVACY AND SECURITY?T OF 14
Design and Performance of the OpenBSD Statefull Packet Filter Slides
The role of cellular polysaccharides in the formation and stability of aerobic granules
20150327 The Personality and Power of the Antichrist (Dan 8 15 27) ETSD06

więcej podobnych podstron